Risk Preferences in Participative Budgeting

This study examines participative budgeting in the context of the psychology of risk. As Young (1985) and Waller (1988) report, there is some preliminary evidence that risk-averse workers create more budgetary slack than risk-neutral ones. They show that "truth inducing incentive schemes"...

Ausführliche Beschreibung

Bibliographische Detailangaben
Veröffentlicht in:The Accounting Review. - American Accounting Association. - 67(1992), 2, Seite 303-318
1. Verfasser: Kim, D. C. (VerfasserIn)
Format: Online-Aufsatz
Sprache:English
Veröffentlicht: 1992
Zugriff auf das übergeordnete Werk:The Accounting Review
Schlagworte:Participative budgeting Risk preference Prospect theory Budgeting Business Economics Behavioral sciences Philosophy
LEADER 01000caa a22002652 4500
001 JST000422878
003 DE-627
005 20240619090000.0
007 cr uuu---uuuuu
008 150322s1992 xx |||||o 00| ||eng c
035 |a (DE-627)JST000422878 
035 |a (JST)247726 
040 |a DE-627  |b ger  |c DE-627  |e rakwb 
041 |a eng 
100 1 |a Kim, D. C.  |e verfasserin  |4 aut 
245 1 0 |a Risk Preferences in Participative Budgeting 
264 1 |c 1992 
336 |a Text  |b txt  |2 rdacontent 
337 |a Computermedien  |b c  |2 rdamedia 
338 |a Online-Ressource  |b cr  |2 rdacarrier 
520 |a This study examines participative budgeting in the context of the psychology of risk. As Young (1985) and Waller (1988) report, there is some preliminary evidence that risk-averse workers create more budgetary slack than risk-neutral ones. They show that "truth inducing incentive schemes" (e.g., Soviet incentive schemes; see Weitzman 1976) reduce budgetary slack for risk-neutral subjects but not for risk-averse subjects. If this is true, it means that resource allocations within organizations are mediated by perceptions of risk. Young (1985) and Waller (1988) define risk preference as a dispositional variable, which presumes that it is a stable personal trait, a latent variable, traditionally inferred from observed behavior of risk propensity in such settings like lotteries. This study tests whether risk preferences are domain-specific; that is, latent risk preferences translate into differing manifest risk preferences according to the context. Domain-specific risk preference can be understood as a manifest psychological variable that may well be the result of the combination of latent risk propensity and the situation. Kahneman and Tversky's prospect theory (1979) suggests that manifest risk preferences depend upon whether the subject frames his or her task in the context of gain or loss prospects, where gains and losses are defined in relation to a neutral reference point. If risk preferences are domain-specific, then past studies' suggestion that incentive schemes should be designed in consideration of dispositional, or latent, risk preferences needs to be reexamined (Waller 1988; Kaplan 1982). The question before this study is: If subordinates are influenced by prior period performance in setting current period budgets for themselves, will that influence take the form predicted by prospect theory and thus lead to riskier preferences (tight budgets) when the subordinates perceive themselves in a losing situation? This is an important question considering Young's (1985) alluding to the possibility that inducing subordinates to less risk-averse behavior may be a way to favor tight budgetary standards and reduce slack. This prediction is consistent with prospect theory's implication that losers who are slow to adjust their reference point act in a more risk-seeking manner. Thus, the induction of losing prospects might be a way to minimize budgetary slack. An additional concern in this study is to jointly test domain-specific risk preferences and dispositions toward risk as influences over budgetary decisions. Whereas prospect theory explains risk preferences as domain-specific contingencies, other theories construe risk preferences as dispositional. It is likely that both domain-specific and dispositional factors influence budgetary decisions. This study deploys a conventional lottery procedure to elicit and test dispositions toward risk. An experiment simulating the public accountants' budgeting of billable hours was designed to test the hypothesis that subject preference for tight or safe budget behavior depends on the performance of coworkers and domain-specific risk preferences. The hypotheses were tested in an experiment employing 81 students. The results generally support the view that subordinates' risk preferences are influenced by a situation-dependent variable. The reversal of risk preferences around a neutral reference point is statistically significant for both dispositionally risk-averse and dispositionally risk-seeking subjects. The dispositional variable also contributes to the explanation of variations in subjects' manifest risk preferences. Thus the propensity to induce budgetary slack seems to be a joint function of situations and dispositions. 
540 |a Copyright American Accounting Association 
650 4 |a Participative budgeting 
650 4 |a Risk preference 
650 4 |a Prospect theory 
650 4 |a Budgeting 
650 4 |a Business  |x Accountancy  |x Financial accounting  |x Budgeting  |x Financial budgets 
650 4 |a Economics  |x Economic disciplines  |x Financial economics  |x Finance  |x Financial analysis  |x Risk management  |x Risk preferences 
650 4 |a Behavioral sciences  |x Behavioral economics  |x Prospect theory 
650 4 |a Economics  |x Economic disciplines  |x Financial economics  |x Finance  |x Financial management  |x Financial risk 
650 4 |a Economics  |x Microeconomics  |x Economic utility  |x Expected utility 
650 4 |a Business  |x Accountancy  |x Financial accounting  |x Budgeting 
650 4 |a Business  |x Accountancy  |x Financial accounting  |x Budgeting  |x Budgetary slack 
650 4 |a Philosophy  |x Epistemology  |x Empiricism  |x Empirical evidence 
650 4 |a Business  |x Accountancy  |x Auditing  |x Financial audits  |x Tax audits 
650 4 |a Behavioral sciences  |x Psychology  |x Cognitive psychology  |x Cognitive processes  |x Decision making  |x Choice architecture  |x Framing effects 
655 4 |a research-article 
773 0 8 |i Enthalten in  |t The Accounting Review  |d American Accounting Association  |g 67(1992), 2, Seite 303-318  |w (DE-627)338766812  |w (DE-600)2064580-6  |x 00014826  |7 nnns 
773 1 8 |g volume:67  |g year:1992  |g number:2  |g pages:303-318 
856 4 0 |u https://www.jstor.org/stable/247726  |3 Volltext 
912 |a GBV_USEFLAG_A 
912 |a SYSFLAG_A 
912 |a GBV_JST 
912 |a GBV_ILN_11 
912 |a GBV_ILN_20 
912 |a GBV_ILN_22 
912 |a GBV_ILN_23 
912 |a GBV_ILN_24 
912 |a GBV_ILN_31 
912 |a GBV_ILN_32 
912 |a GBV_ILN_39 
912 |a GBV_ILN_40 
912 |a GBV_ILN_60 
912 |a GBV_ILN_62 
912 |a GBV_ILN_63 
912 |a GBV_ILN_65 
912 |a GBV_ILN_69 
912 |a GBV_ILN_70 
912 |a GBV_ILN_73 
912 |a GBV_ILN_74 
912 |a GBV_ILN_90 
912 |a GBV_ILN_95 
912 |a GBV_ILN_100 
912 |a GBV_ILN_105 
912 |a GBV_ILN_110 
912 |a GBV_ILN_120 
912 |a GBV_ILN_121 
912 |a GBV_ILN_150 
912 |a GBV_ILN_151 
912 |a GBV_ILN_152 
912 |a GBV_ILN_161 
912 |a GBV_ILN_171 
912 |a GBV_ILN_187 
912 |a GBV_ILN_206 
912 |a GBV_ILN_213 
912 |a GBV_ILN_224 
912 |a GBV_ILN_230 
912 |a GBV_ILN_285 
912 |a GBV_ILN_293 
912 |a GBV_ILN_370 
912 |a GBV_ILN_374 
912 |a GBV_ILN_602 
912 |a GBV_ILN_636 
912 |a GBV_ILN_702 
912 |a GBV_ILN_2001 
912 |a GBV_ILN_2003 
912 |a GBV_ILN_2005 
912 |a GBV_ILN_2006 
912 |a GBV_ILN_2007 
912 |a GBV_ILN_2008 
912 |a GBV_ILN_2009 
912 |a GBV_ILN_2010 
912 |a GBV_ILN_2011 
912 |a GBV_ILN_2014 
912 |a GBV_ILN_2015 
912 |a GBV_ILN_2018 
912 |a GBV_ILN_2020 
912 |a GBV_ILN_2021 
912 |a GBV_ILN_2025 
912 |a GBV_ILN_2026 
912 |a GBV_ILN_2027 
912 |a GBV_ILN_2031 
912 |a GBV_ILN_2034 
912 |a GBV_ILN_2037 
912 |a GBV_ILN_2038 
912 |a GBV_ILN_2039 
912 |a GBV_ILN_2043 
912 |a GBV_ILN_2044 
912 |a GBV_ILN_2048 
912 |a GBV_ILN_2049 
912 |a GBV_ILN_2050 
912 |a GBV_ILN_2055 
912 |a GBV_ILN_2056 
912 |a GBV_ILN_2057 
912 |a GBV_ILN_2059 
912 |a GBV_ILN_2061 
912 |a GBV_ILN_2064 
912 |a GBV_ILN_2065 
912 |a GBV_ILN_2068 
912 |a GBV_ILN_2070 
912 |a GBV_ILN_2086 
912 |a GBV_ILN_2093 
912 |a GBV_ILN_2098 
912 |a GBV_ILN_2106 
912 |a GBV_ILN_2107 
912 |a GBV_ILN_2108 
912 |a GBV_ILN_2111 
912 |a GBV_ILN_2112 
912 |a GBV_ILN_2113 
912 |a GBV_ILN_2116 
912 |a GBV_ILN_2118 
912 |a GBV_ILN_2122 
912 |a GBV_ILN_2125 
912 |a GBV_ILN_2129 
912 |a GBV_ILN_2143 
912 |a GBV_ILN_2145 
912 |a GBV_ILN_2147 
912 |a GBV_ILN_2148 
912 |a GBV_ILN_2152 
912 |a GBV_ILN_2153 
912 |a GBV_ILN_2158 
912 |a GBV_ILN_2188 
912 |a GBV_ILN_2190 
912 |a GBV_ILN_2232 
912 |a GBV_ILN_2336 
912 |a GBV_ILN_2446 
912 |a GBV_ILN_2470 
912 |a GBV_ILN_2472 
912 |a GBV_ILN_2507 
912 |a GBV_ILN_2548 
912 |a GBV_ILN_2809 
912 |a GBV_ILN_2935 
912 |a GBV_ILN_2940 
912 |a GBV_ILN_2949 
912 |a GBV_ILN_2950 
912 |a GBV_ILN_4012 
912 |a GBV_ILN_4035 
912 |a GBV_ILN_4037 
912 |a GBV_ILN_4046 
912 |a GBV_ILN_4112 
912 |a GBV_ILN_4125 
912 |a GBV_ILN_4126 
912 |a GBV_ILN_4242 
912 |a GBV_ILN_4246 
912 |a GBV_ILN_4249 
912 |a GBV_ILN_4251 
912 |a GBV_ILN_4277 
912 |a GBV_ILN_4305 
912 |a GBV_ILN_4306 
912 |a GBV_ILN_4307 
912 |a GBV_ILN_4313 
912 |a GBV_ILN_4322 
912 |a GBV_ILN_4323 
912 |a GBV_ILN_4324 
912 |a GBV_ILN_4325 
912 |a GBV_ILN_4326 
912 |a GBV_ILN_4333 
912 |a GBV_ILN_4335 
912 |a GBV_ILN_4338 
912 |a GBV_ILN_4346 
912 |a GBV_ILN_4367 
912 |a GBV_ILN_4392 
912 |a GBV_ILN_4393 
912 |a GBV_ILN_4700 
912 |a GBV_ILN_4753 
951 |a AR 
952 |d 67  |j 1992  |e 2  |h 303-318